This article appears in the October 27, 2000 issue of Executive Intelligence Review.
The Quality Adjustment Method:
How Statistical Fakery Wipes Out Inflation
by Richard Freeman
The actual U.S. rate of inflation is higher by 3 times or more, than the
Consumer Price Index (CPI) official rate of 3.4% posted by the Bureau of Labor
Statistics of the U.S. Department of Labor. The CPI is corrupted by the Quality
Adjustment Method (formerly called the Quality Adjustment Factor), which covers
up and hides inflation, and also distorts U.S. Gross Domestic Product and
industrial production.
Americans and others are kept in the dark about the U.S.
inflation rate through the debasing influence of the Quality Adjustment Method
(QAM). Perhaps one citizen in 100,000 has heard of the QAM, yet the Department
of Labor, Department of Commerce, and the U.S. Federal Reserve Board of
Governors each has a staff devoted predominantly to the application of this
method of statistical fraud.
The successful functioning of the U.S. economy is
incompatible with the continued application of the QAM. Introduced in 1967 by
the financier oligarchy during Arthur Burns's regime at the Federal Reserve, and
spread by statisticians, it is set up to exclude anywhere from one-quarter to
three-quarters of true inflation. It works from the continuous assumption
that the quality of goods is improving: therefore, if the price of a product
rose 10%, and the statisticians of the BLS claim two-thirds of the price
increase was due to improved quality (the veracity of that statement will be
explored below), the inflation of that product's price is reported as only
3.3%
But this is only half the use of the QAM; it represents
another major problem. As Lyndon LaRouche shows in this Feature, any
accounting system that attempts to measure footprints of economic activity,
rather than the transformative activity of human beings who make the footprints,
has a fundamental problem.
The pricing results of the Quality Adjustment Method, once
fabricated, are turned over the Commerce Department's Bureau of Economic
Analysis. The BEA makes the assumption that improved quality is the equivalent
of increased output. So, if it is assumed that the quality of the product
cited above improved by 6.7% per year, then the output is assumed to have
increased by 6.7% (or more) per year. The BEA will apply this method to hundreds
of products, and the increased output attributed to each of these products is
added to Gross Domestic Product (GDP). That is a prime reason why real physical
production is falling, but GDP is rising.
Further, the QAM is turned over to the Federal Reserve Board
of Governors, which publishes the Industrial Production Index. The Fed uses the
QAM to "increase" industrial production in a manner similar to the Department of
Commerce's hiking of GDP.
Therefore, the QAM is central in the calculation of three of
the most important and closely-watched gauges of the economy: inflation, GDP,
and industrial production. The fraud of pervades each of these three.
Exposing the QAM
Lyndon LaRouche and EIR brought to light the
charlatanry of the Quality Adjustment Method in 1983 (see R. Freeman, "`Quality
Adjustment Factor': How the Fed Hides Inflation," EIR, Oct. 4, 1983). On
Feb. 4, 1984, then-Democratic Party Presidential pre-candidate LaRouche brought
the exposé of the QAM to the nation in a half-hour broadcast on ABC
television. LaRouche said: "At the end of the first quarter of 1983, we were
shocked to notice that both the Federal Reserve and Bureau of Labor Statistics
were faking the figures for both industrial output and for unemployment by very
wide margins. Later, we discovered also that the reported rate of inflation was
being faked as well. It was being faked by as much as three times, that is, the
rate of inflation during 1983 was about three times as much as the government
has reported to you."
While the QAM is a statistical fraud of considerable
importance, for the City of London-Wall Street financier oligarchy, it takes on
the character of a strategic weapon. Three examples stand out.
First, it is being used to loot the American population. More
than 100 million Americans are covered by cost-of-living adjustments in their
wage contracts, and programs such as Social Security, Medicare, Unemployment
Insurance, etc., which are supposed to protect them against inflation.
EIR has calculated that BLS lying about the rate of inflation, in which
the QAM plays a great role, has this year stolen between $278 and $328 billion
from these Americans.
Second, the QAM is being applied to cover up the hideous
consequences of the policy adopted by Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan
Greenspan. In the third quarter 1998, acting on behalf of the financier
oligarchy, Greenspan desperately revved up the printing presses, in order to
hold up the bloated mass of speculative financial property titles, which were at
the point of disintegration following the September 1998 Long Term Capital
Management hedge-fund failure. That policy put the world on the path toward a
hyperinflationary spiral, which will have the same devastating consequences as
the hyperinflation which ravaged Weimar Germany from March through November
1923. Even though the prices of basic commodities, such as oil and
polyvinylchloride, and consumer products, such as housing, are rising in the
range of 15% to 180% per year, the BLS insists that inflation is only
3.4%.
Third, the QAM is a vital element in the fake claim of a U.S.
"noninflationary economic expansion." The QAM underreports inflation, and helps
overstate GDP and industrial production. The lie of economic growth has a
strategic implication: it is being employed to draw foreign funds into the
United States, to cover over a projected $430 billion annual current account
deficit in 2000. This foreign funds inflow helps the United States to hold up
the value of the dollar and to import a large volume of goods. Were the myth
about the U.S. economy shattered, it would precipitate a dollar crisis and the
withdrawal of foreign funds, which would puncture the U.S. financial
system.
How the QAM Distorts Inflation
The QAM is used to adjust the reporting of prices on both a
producer level and on a retail/consumer level. The BLS reports two types of
price indexes: the Producer Price Index (PPI), which measures the change of
price of a good at the producer level; and the Consumer Price Index (CPI), which
measures the change of price of a market basket of goods at the retail level.
Both divisions work on the same principle.
Between 1980 and 1981, for example, the average transaction
price of a new car rose from $7,574 to $8,910, an increase of $1,336. Based on
that, it is possible to calculate the rate of car-price inflation for 1981, at
17.6%, a very substantial increase.
But the wizards at the BLS got rid of most of that increase.
In a BLS document, "Quality Changes for Passenger Cars, 1969-99," the BLS
initially attributed 99% of the price increase to "improved quality." Then,
after it made further adjustments, the BLS finally attributed 66% of the 1981
increase in the price of a car to "improved quality," and 34% to actual price
increase. The BLS reported to the BEA, that only $454 of the $1,336 price
increase in 1981 was actually an increase in price. Thus, the BLS threw away
two-thirds, or $882, of the price increase you paid in 1981. It reported an
auto-price inflation rate of just 6.0%.
What is considered improved quality? There are various things
that the BLS, and other agencies consider quality improvements, including: a new
catalytic converter to meet an "air-quality-emissions" code set by the Congress;
the change of a material from a metal to plastic; the change of a truck to a
sport utility vehicle; the "upgrading" of a "convenience package," which might
include power door locks, a security alarm, power steering and power seats, or
the introduction of CD players. In effect, the manufacturer is allowed to deduct
all his costs in these areas (which costs he has passed on to consumers), from
the BLS reporting of his price.
Many of what are counted as improvements, are not
improvements at all. Consider the overall construction of a car. Since 1967,
there has been a general reduction in the weight of a car by more than one-third
of a ton. In part, this has been done in order to increase mileage efficiency.
Yet, despite the lies of the Naderites, highway safety tests show that lighter
cars suffer far worse damage in collisions with cars which weigh 3,000 pounds or
more, or with inanimate objects, such as trees or walls.
The recasting of light trucks into sports utility vehicles is
no improvement, as the fundamental design flaw in the Ford Explorer SUV shows.
That SUV has a tendency to roll over under certain speed and load conditions,
and, when paired with Firestone tires, has resulted in many unnecessary deaths.
The "upgrading" of a convenience package, so that a car has a better security
alarm or other accessories, does not constitute a fundamental
improvement.
The Reality of Product Improvement
But let us grant, for a moment, that all the above-alleged
improvements were improvements. For centuries in America, there have been
improvements in the quality of products, and crucially, in the production and
engineering processes which generated those improved products. This is not an
exception, but the normal feature of a developing society. The basis of all
economics starts with the sovereign individual mind creating new validatable
scientific discoveries of fundamental principle. These discoveries are then
transmitted into the economy through newly incorporated scientific advances in
machine-tool design, or upgraded infrastructure. In America, during periods when
revolutionary advance in machine-tool design improved products, this was
considered normal. The revolutionary process would reduce the actual price paid
for products.
Then in 1967, the QAM was manufactured by the oligarchy at
the time of a paradigm shift imposed on the United States toward a
post-industrial society. The fact that this shift would build a speculative
bubble, which would feed inflation, had to be concealed somehow.
In the development of the automobile, since the 1890s, many
fundamental improvements were made, from the electric starter motor, replacing
the hand crank, around 1911-12; to the system of transmission to replace the
earlier direct linkage of the engine to the driving wheels; to the introduction
of the independent front suspension as universal during the 1930s; to the myriad
progressions in engine design and function. There was a revolution in the
automobile, in particular, up through 1950.
But since 1967, when the QAM was instituted, the improvements
have not been of the dimension of the accumulated fundamental changes of the
period from 1890 through 1950. Why should there be a QAM after 1967, when most
of the fundamental changes occurred before 1967? There is no need for a QAM. In
fact, for nearly two centuries of the history of the United States until 1967,
there was no QAM for anything, and for a sound reason: Improved quality should
be treated as an inherent feature of a healthy economy.
In fact, since 1967, several fundamental features of the car
have deteriorated, not improved. Cars which weigh one-third to one-half ton less
than they did 30 years ago, are more likely to sustain more serious damage to
the car and passenger, when they collide with a stationary object. In many
instances, the cost of car repair, because of the design problem of the cars,
has risen sharply.
Now, let us return to what has happened in the reporting of
the increase of car prices, considered over the period 1967-99. Figure
1 shows that, according to the BEA, the average transaction price
of a new car was $3,216 in 1967 (the BEA bases its data on a survey of 125 car
models every year). By 1999, the transaction price of a new car had jumped to
$20,658. This is the price that a consumer pays for a car--an increase of 6.42
times.
In the same figure, using the same starting point on the
graph, look at the BLS Consumer Price Index for the cost of a new car. Based on
an index, in which the value of the years 1982-84 is set equal to 100, the index
level was at 49.3 in 1967. By 1999, the index had trudged up to 139.6--an
increase of only 2.83 times.
Compare the two curves. They're both supposed to be measuring
the same thing, but the curve of the transaction price of a new car represents
reality: what makes the path of the CPI curve so much slower, is the QAM. The
CPI index for the cost of a new car only accounted for 44% of the actual price
increase over the past 30-plus years. It attributed 56% of the actual price
increase to alleged "improved quality," and excluded it from counting. Between
1967 and 1999, the actual increase of the price of a new car was 2.27 times
greater than what the CPI fraudulently reported.
Figure 2 shows the ability of the BLS to
cut down inflation. The first bar graph shows that the transaction cost of a new
car was $3,216 in 1967. It then shows what the car would cost in 1999 if it had
been "adjusted" by the CPI index: $9,101. No such vehicle was to be found in
1999, even by believers in the statistics of the BLS. It is only in its
published reports that the BLS "made disappear" the $11,557 in the actual cost
of a car.
A BLS analyst reported on Oct. 10, "The BLS has quality
adjustments for probably thousands of products." Every home appliance has a
quality adjustment, as do furniture and clothing, the home itself,
telecommunications equipment and computers (the quality adjustment for the
computer is called the hedonic index, as will be reported below).
Additional Distortions of Inflation
But the BLS has still other weapons to "reduce" inflation. In
the 1990s, the Senate Finance Committee established the Advisory Commission to
Study the Consumer Price Index, which was staffed by people whose aim was to
reduce the inflation rate further, through various shams and ruses. The
Commission issued its final report on Dec. 4, 1996, calling for a series of
changes which would lower the CPI by 1.1%. In January 1999, the BLS instituted
one of these changes, called the "consumer substitution" change. This assumes
that if prices rise, the consumer will strive to make a constant level of
expenditures for a certain category of goods. So, if the price of one item goes
up, the consumer will substitute another item, which is cheaper. This may not be
at all what happens in reality; but, the BLS made an assumption, which
pre-programs in that the consumer would not be paying more for certain
categories of goods. A spokesman for the BLS told EIR on Sept. 11, 2000,
that this assumption alone will permanently take 0.2% per year off the CPI
rate.
By use of such gimmicks, and above all the QAM, the BLS has
whittled down consumer inflation, from August 1999 through August 2000, to an
average of 3.4%. But, as EIR has reported, the rate of inflation for
certain commodities, such as housing, energy, etc., has risen at rates of
15-180% per year. EIR estimates that the true rate of inflation is 10%,
three times the official rate.
The oligarchs, and their hired statisticians, are aware of
what lying about inflation does. The Advisory Commission to Study the Consumer
Price Index, in its December 1996 final report, stated, "Corrections . . . in
the CPI . . . would also contribute importantly to reductions in federal budget
deficits and the national debt." In particular, "reductions" would cause "lower
outlays," which would be lower through "cuts in indexed federal spending
programs." That means that many federal programs, such as Social Security,
Medicare, Unemployment Insurance, Food Stamps, and so forth, are adjusted by a
cost-of-living adjustment, which is pegged to the CPI. By artificially cutting
the CPI, the cost-of-living adjustment is lowered, and the expenditures for
these programs are lowered. EIR documented in a Sept. 28 study, that
lying about inflation in this way will gouge between $278 and $328 billion from
the U.S. population in 2000 (see "Lies About Inflation Are Being Used to Loot
the Population").
The QAM Manipulates GDP Growth
But once the QAM is used to depress the reported level of
inflation, it is then used to pump up the level of GDP, and in parallel, the
Industrial Production Index.
Let us consider the question of computers and accessories,
including software. It is the QAM modification of computers and accessories that
had an enormous false effect on alleged U.S. GDP growth.
On Oct. 11, an analyst at the National Income and Wealth
Division of the Bureau of Economic Analysis of the Department of Commerce,
explained how the QAM index for computers is used to increase GDP. It is the
same principle by which the QAM for other products is used to increase GDP. The
pith of the conversation has been presented in Table 1.
Assume, stated the analyst, that in the United States, in 1998, total U.S.
computer sales were $100 billion, in current (nominal) dollars, and in 1999,
total U.S. computer sales were $100 billion in current (nominal) dollars. This
is line 1 in Table 1. Assume further, he said, that computers as a whole were
"20% more powerful" in 1999, than they were in 1998. Then, one assumes that
computers cost 20% less in 1999 than they did in 1998. This is standard QAM
procedure, and one deducts 20% from the Producer Price Index for computers in
1999. So, if the producer price index for computers was equal to 100 in 1998, it
would be set equal to 80 in 1999. This example assumes that the actual price of
a computer has not fallen; it is the quality adjustment that has lowered the
price.
However, the analyst now posited a second step, now taken by
the Commerce Department: to increase GDP growth. As a result of the QAM, the
price of the computers in 1999 is only 80% of what it was in 1998. Therefore, he
explained, the output in 1999, of $100 billion, is worth more. He proposed
dividing $100 billion by 0.8 (80%), and this yields a new adjusted output of
computers in 1999 of $125 billion (that is, $100 billion divided by 0.8). The
rationale is that if prices are only 80% of what they appear to be in 1999, then
the $100 billion in current dollars output is only 80% of what the adjusted
output would be, $125 billion. Thus, by use of the QAM, computer output in 1999
has been increased from $100 billion to $125 billion; this represents an
increase of 25%. So, the analyst pointed out, prices fell by 20%, but output
increased by 25%, through the application of the QAM.
With computers, a process called the hedonic index is
applied. In its application to prices, it has the same conceptual overview as
the QAM, but there are a few differences. To explain the hedonic index briefly:
A computer is thought of as a bundle of characteristics, such as speed,
expandable memory, CD drive, etc. In the case where a computer exists in 1999,
but a comparable computer did not exist in 1996, then the BEA constructs an
"imputed" computer model for 1996, which has the same characteristics, features,
and performance as the computer that exists in 1999. Each characteristic has a
coefficient that links it to the computer's overall price. An "imputed" price
for the 1996 computer is constructed. It is then compared to the 1999 computer.
A prime purpose is to compare the prices of the two computers, so that a quality
adjustment can be made, showing how superior the 1999 computer is to the 1996
computer.
Some years, computers' prices fall; some years, they rise.
But using the hedonic method, as a form of the QAM, the Commerce Department
always makes the price of a computer fall 3 to 4 times what it actually fell, if
it did fall (or, it makes it fall, if the actual price rose). What the BEA is
most interested in, is using a big quality-adjusted fall in price, to create a
big quality-adjusted increase in output.
Now, we will look at what effect the hedonic adjustment/
quality adjustment upon computers, had on GDP. We will look at this in
conjunction with the fact that the United States, alone among major countries,
counts computer software as a form of capital spending/investment. That fact,
together with hedonic adjustment, made up a huge amount of the supposed increase
of real GDP in the United States, between the second quarter of 1998 and the
second quarter of 2000.
The predominant way of computing GDP is by the method of the
"expenditure system." This adds together four elements: 1) Gross Private
Domestic Investment, which includes business capital investment; 2) Personal
Consumption Expenditures, which represents personal or consumer expenditures for
consumer/personal goods or services; 3) Government Expenditures; and 4) Net
Exports. Items 1 and 2 make up the bulk of GDP, and here we are concerned with
item 1.
The business expenditure for computers, which is classified
as capital investment, is counted as part of Gross Private Domestic Investment.
If it rises, GDP rises. Table 2 shows the Commerce
Department's report of the level of business capital investment for computers.
It is expressed two ways: in current dollars, and in real (chained) 1996
inflation-adjusted dollars. In the case of the real (chained) 1996
inflation-adjusted dollars, this has already been subjected to the hedonic index
quality adjustment. Business capital investment for computers, when stated in
current actual dollars, rose, between the second quarter of 1998 and the second
quarter of 2000, from $85.5 billion to $114.2 billion, an increase of $28.7
billion. However, when stated in 1996 (chained) inflation-adjusted dollars, the
same business capital investment for computers rose, between the second quarter
of 1998 and the second quarter of 2000, from $144.0 billion to $298.5 billion,
an increase of $154.5 billion.
Amazingly, one can see that business capital investment for
computers rose by $125.8 billion more ($154.5 billion minus $28.7 billion), when
stated in 1996 (chained) inflation-adjusted dollars than when stated in current
dollars. But this is the same capital investment! The reason for this is the
application of the QAM/hedonic index, which took a $28.7 billion increase in
actual current dollars, and turned it into a $154.5 billion increase in "real"
inflation-adjusted dollars. The QAM/hedonic index, all by itself, caused the
increase in the level of business expenditure in capital investment for
computers, to grow five-fold. The QAM/hedonic index manufactured a counterfeit
$125.8 billion increase in alleged business capital spending for
computers.
Now, add in the second element, that the United States is
alone among major nations in counting business expenditures for computer
software as if it were a capital investment. Between the second quarter 1998 and
the second quarter 2000, when stated in 1996 (chained) inflation-adjusted
dollars, the business expenditure for so-called capital investment in computer
software rose from $146.7 billion to $227.5 billion, an increase of $80.8
billion. This increase of $80.8 billion increased the capital investment portion
of the Gross Domestic Private Investment part of GDP. This in turn increased
GDP. But in all other major nations, this investment in computer software would
be counted as a business expense, and not as a capital investment, and therefore
it would not increase GDP. Therefore, the increase in capital investment for
computer software of $80.8 billion is a fake, unique to the United
States.
For the period between the second quarter 1998 and the second
quarter 2000, Table 3 lists the counterfeit $125.8 billion
increase in business expenditures for capital investment in computers which is
due solely to the QAM/hedonic index; the $80.8 billion increase in capital
investment for computer software, which is fake and unique to the United States;
and the increase of total GDP of the United States in real 1996
inflation-adjusted dollars, of $843.2 billion. The combination of these first
two items totals $206.6 billion. Thus, between the second quarter 1998 and the
second quarter 2000, these two bits of fakery made up 24.5% of all the alleged
real GDP growth of the United States.
But that is just the beginning. In addition to computers, the
Quality Adjustment Method is applied to thousands of other products, which
artificially increases the alleged output of GDP. This is true for cars, houses,
household appliances, furniture, and so forth. A significant part of alleged GDP
growth is due to the application of the QAM.
But GDP has deep methodological flaws, and does not measure
the performance of the real economy. A good part of GDP growth is the
speculative financial cancer, and non-productive overhead services, which is
embellished by much statistical foolery. The QAM is central here.
Yet, the story does not end there. The QAM is turned over to
the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, which publishes the Industrial
Production Index. According to a discussion with Carol Corrado, chief of the
Industrial Output Section at the Federal Reserve, on Oct. 10, the Federal
Reserve follows the basic method of the Commerce Department, and uses the QAM to
increase the reported industrial production of different sectors of the
economy.
Thus, the QAM fraud is central in three of the most important
parts of the economy--inflation, GDP, and industrial production. It invalidates
much that is published about any of these areas. It is a piece of statistical
fakery that is destroying the nation.
|
|